Last week’s employment situation report showed that employer payrolls increased by 266,000 people on a seasonally adjusted basis. This number was lower than many people expected and, in response, many pundits began calling for cuts to unemployment benefits on the theory that they are to blame for the lackluster payroll growth.

Weak Support for Conclusion

As I indicated on Friday, these pundit conclusions don’t actually follow from this data. The question of whether, and by how much, unemployment benefits are reducing the number of people willing to accept work is a question of employment flows not employment levels.

Net job growth can be lower than expected because fewer out-of-work people are taking jobs or because more in-work people are losing jobs. But only the former may indicate that unemployment benefits are reducing the number of people willing to accept work and, when we look only at that figure, we see that the number of people who newly found employment actually went up from 6.464 million in March to 6.9 million in April. The lackluster net job growth in April was driven, not by people staying on unemployment, but rather women leaving their jobs and exiting the labor force altogether.

Kalecki on Full Employment

With this all said, I think it is important as this debate develops over the next few months to remain clear about what is meant by the phrase “full employment” as it will no doubt be misleadingly seized upon by advocates of welfare cuts.

In one meaning of the term, “full employment” just means employing every potential worker in the country. If there are 3 million people who could work but aren’t, then you don’t have full employment, and that’s bad because you are not maximizing production and employment in the economy. Under this meaning of the term, if cutting unemployment benefits pushes more people into jobs, it moves the country closer to full employment.

In a second meaning of the term, “full employment” refers to a labor market situation where employers have a hard time finding people to hire. This is what Kalecki meant by the term in his canonical text “The Political Aspects of Full Employment.”

The maintenance of full employment would cause social and political changes which would give a new impetus to the opposition of the business leaders. Indeed, under a regime of permanent full employment, the “sack” would cease to play its role as a disciplinary measure. The social position of the boss would be undermined, and the self-assurance and class-consciousness of the working class would grow. Strikes for wage increases and improvements in conditions of work would create political tension.

One reason why employers might have a hard time finding people to hire is because they are already in a job. But another reason is that they are subsisting on non-labor incomes (capital income, old-age pensions, disability pensions, unemployment insurance, etc.) and would rather do that than take the job that the employer is trying to fill under the terms the employer is offering.

In this meaning of the term, cutting unemployment benefits in order to push people into accepting work brings the country further away from “full employment.” It increases labor supply, makes it easier for employers to fill vacancies, and makes it easier for employers to fire people and threaten to fire people. It increases the power of bosses while decreasing the power of workers.

It is this latter worker-power-focused approach to “full employment” that the left has been historically interested in and that the left should continue to push in the coming year. Workers choosing to holdout while they have decent income to support them is not the same thing as a worker with little to no income searching in vain to find a job. Both show up as lower employment, but the former is generally good while the latter is generally bad.

Where precisely to set the parameters of an unemployment benefit system is not something that can be derived totally abstractly from ideologies and theories. You want a benefit that cushions everyone when they lose a job and provides them ample time and opportunity to look for work that they think is suitable. But you also want most people moving off the rolls after a while and you don’t want the rolls to be so big that it is really putting a damper on crucial production that people need to live.

When looking at the unemployment rolls as they currently stand, it is hard to see why anyone would be especially alarmed by them. Benefit levels are decent and people do have a decent amount of time (I’d say too little) to look for work they think is suitable. People are moving off the rolls in significant numbers and the rolls are really not that large in the grand scheme of the economy.

The UI situation seems totally fine all things considered. The case for cuts is weak on all levels, but especially weak if you are interested in full employment in the Kaleckian sense of the word. Impoverishing people to flush them into jobs they are reluctant to accept is not good for those moved off the rolls, not good for those who are already in work, and especially not good for those who are still unable to find a job but now receive much lower or no benefits while they search.